Risk Management: When the Dollar Is No Longer King

“The dollar is our currency but your problem,” Jim Connolly said in 1971 when he was US Secretary of Treasury.

 
Following the US sovereign downgrade and a commitment to an exceptionally loose monetary policy, this problem has become an even bigger headache for emerging market central banks with large holdings of USD assets. We discuss these issues and the diversification choices available to emerging market policymakers in this article.
 
Our main conclusions are:
  • It is wrong to assume that a reserve currency can remain one regardless of the underlying macro policies. The diminution of the British pound in the early to mid-1900s is a case in point.

 

  • In the current context, portfolio risks of staying in US treasuries have increased. Neither can the US remain a dominant driver of emerging market exports.

 

  • Reducing the pace of reserve accumulation would be the most practical solution to this problem. Additionally, there is scope for increasing allocations in alternate currencies, the Swiss franc and emerging market local currency bonds.

 

  • Local currency bond markets are small but rapidly growing.
 
The old order
The Bretton Woods 2 system is an informal international monetary system that has existed over the last decade or so.
 
The broad contours of the system are as follows:
  • By running a large current account deficit, the US economy is a source of export growth/employment for emerging markets.

 

  • The deficit is funded by systematic intervention in the foreign exchange markets by emerging market central banks, which also provide the external financing required by the US to fund the deficit.

 

  • Accumulating large amounts of foreign currency reserves in the form of dollar assets such as treasuries was also viewed favourably by emerging market central banks – particularly Asian central banks – in the aftermath of the 1997/98 financial crisis. Such accumulation was regarded as a form of ‘self-insurance’ against future speculative attacks.
 

The durability of this system is now being challenged. The system no longer represents the old symbiosis of interests. As should be inevitable with the level and duration of de-leveraging needed, the growth potential of the US has deteriorated and the current account gap is being structurally downsized.

 

This adjustment will have a lasting impact on emerging market exports, regardless of the monetary arrangements. And indeed, trade data suggests that the role of the US as the marginal driver of emerging market exports is diminishing, as shown by the chart below.

 
US non-fuel imports from emerging markets
 
 
Emerging self-reliance
The evolving growth model for emerging markets and for Asia in particular, which is the main counter-party to the US in Bretton Woods 2, is one of self-reliance.
 
Policymakers in this region are strengthening domestic demand via expansionary fiscal and wage policies, although these policies are inadequate or have natural limits. Reserve accumulation by definition compresses domestic demand and therefore, offsets the impact of expansionary domestic policies.
 
A second challenge comes from the rising risks associated with holding the dollar as a reserve currency. There are two major risks: the deterioration in America’s public finances and the associated sovereign downgrade, and more importantly, in our view, America’s exceptionally generous monetary policy.
 
The Fed has pre-committed to a near zero policy rate for the next two years almost immediately after a large dose of quantitative easing. The net result has been a marked deterioration in the value of the dollar to gold (see chart below), as well as diminished currency-adjusted returns on treasuries.
 
The situation partly reflects that in the 1970s, when the dollar was devalued vis-à-vis gold from US$35 to US$38 per ounce.
 
Gold and US Dollar Index (DXY) ratio
 

 

By contrast, emerging markets have both better government balance-sheets and more contained monetary policies. As evident in the table below, US fundamentals on the basis of public indebtedness and the increase in the reserve-money-to-GDP ratio are significantly worse than that of most emerging markets.

 

Foreign exchange reserves and public debt
 
 
Demise of Bretton Woods 2
It is now clear that Bretton Woods 2 has run its course and something’s gotta give. But what and at what pace?
 
On the second question, there is little doubt that the pace of any change will need to be gradual. Emerging markets – non-Japan Asia, Brazil and Russia – hold roughly US$1.97 trillion of  US Treasuries. This is equivalent to 38% of their external reserves. A rapid sell-out of treasuries would result in significant capital and foreign-exchange translation losses.
 
The most desirable and practical change is a slower pace of reserve accumulation. This does not have to be deliberate. As emerging markets raise the share of domestic demand in GDP, an inevitable side effect will be reduced savings and, by implication, lower current account surpluses. In Asia, this trend already seems to have set in, as shown by the chart below.
  
Non-Japan Asia current account balances
 
 
There is also scope to diversify incremental reserves with higher allocations to alternate currencies, gold and emerging market bonds.
 
The share of alternate currencies in emerging market reserve allocations has doubled over the last five years. Even so, it remains low at around 5%. Additionally, we note that allocations to the Swiss franc remain low. Much of its recent strength has been driven by private portfolio flows.
 

The renminbi

Local currency bond markets are likely to become more important. According to a recent study by the Asian Development Bank, developing Asia, Brazil and Russia now account for 11.4% of global outstanding bonds, the same as the combined share of France, Germany and the UK.
 
There are a number of obstacles, including the incidence of transactions taxes, limited liquidity and even capital controls. Despite these constraints, however, flows into the emerging market local currency bond space have continued to grow.
 

In a recent statement, the Finance Ministry in Korea said that foreign central participation in local treasuries had increased from 8% to 28% during the 12 months to July 2011. The Bank of Korea is seeking a license as a Qualified Foreign Institutional Investor to invest in China bonds.

 
We should also address one related issue – the role of the RMB. Its convertibility is correctly regarded as a pre-requisite for it to become an alternate to the US dollar. This will remain an issue – the RMB cannot become a convertible currency as long as it is undervalued.
 
Nonetheless, with the development of the CNH (offshore renminbi) market and the more recent permission to repatriate offshore RMB back into the mainland, the scope to invest in RMB products is improving.
 
Overall, we continue to see a diversification of external reserves, even if in a slow and gradual manner. This will gradually diminish the dominance of the USD – a store of value needs to add value.
 
Sterling lessons
At this stage, we are certain some of our readers will be sceptical of our view. Well, history does provide some insight into what can happen.
 
Consider the rise and fall of the GBP. Between 1860 and 1914, around 60% of world trade was invoiced and settled in sterling. This underpinned the reserve currency status of the UK, supported by deep liquid debt/loan markets and GBP bank deposits held by foreigners in London.
 
This is similar to the position of the dollar today – 61% of the world’s foreign currency reserves are denominated in USD, while 86% of foreign exchange transactions are done vis-à-vis the USD.
 
However, by 1913, we started to see the erosion of sterling-denominated foreign exchange reserve holdings. By that time, sterling accounted for less than half of global reserves, while the French franc accounted for around a third and the German mark around a sixth.
 
Sterling’s decline accelerated after World War 1 (1914-18), largely reflecting deteriorating economic fundamentals in the UK. The country had borrowed significant amounts of money (national debt rising from 26.2 % GDP in 1914 to 127.5% of GDP in 1919) to fund the war effort, thereby doubling the amount of money in circulation. One result was excessively high inflation.
 
The gold standard was also abandoned to avoid a large scale exchange of sterling with gold. More contractionary policies were eventually put in place, but by then, sterling had diminished in importance. It was replaced by other currencies including the German mark, French franc and, of course, the dollar. We moved on to a multi-currency world.
 
About the Author
This article is excerpted from “The USD hangover,” a report by Royal Bank of Scotland and affiliated companies that was published on 23 August 2011, and re-edited for clarity and conciseness. This material has been prepared for information purposes only and is not an offer to buy or sell or a solicitation of an offer to buy or sell any security or instrument or to participate in any particular trading strategy.
 
Read more on

Suggested Articles

Some of you might have already been aware of the news that Questex—with the aim to focus on event business—will shut down permanently all media brands in Asia…

Some advice for transitioning into an advisory role

Global risks are intensifying but the collective will to tackle them appears to be lacking. Check out this report for areas of concern